A Downward Spiral? Economics Made Too Simple by STUART KAUFFMAN
Categories: Science and Policy
09:23 am
July 25, 2011
When asked, the great mathematician John von Neumann intuited that money was
somehow related to physical energy.
The intuition has rested there. I believe von Neumann was on the right track and it
probably bears on our current economic mess.
In physics, energy is defined as "the capacity to cause change." The root of this in
physics lies in Newton's three laws of motion.
The first law, we recall, states that a body in motion continues in straight-line motion
at a constant velocity. Newton rests this on the concept of inertia, from Galileo.
Technically, "velocity" includes speed and direction of motion.
The second law of motion is central to us: Any change in straight line motion at a
constant velocity requires an outside force which changes, or "accelerates" that
motion. The famous equation is F = MA. Force equals mass times acceleration,
where acceleration is the rate of change, positive or negative of the speed of motion,
or the direction of motion.
The third law will not concern us: For every action there is an equal and opposite
reaction.
13.7: Cosmos And Culture
Sandra Mu/Getty Images
Cash money
A Downward Spiral? Economics Made Too Simple : 13.7: Cosmos And Culture : NPR Page 1 of 4
http://www.npr.org/blogs/13.7/2011/07/25/138671362/a-downward-spiral-economics-made-too-simple 7/25/2011
It is from the second law which defines force as that which "changes" motion, that we
get with some manipulations, an expression for energy E = 1/2MV squared.
Fine. Some time ago a group of friends including myself and Mike Brown, former
CFO of Microsoft and Chairman of NASDAQ were wondering how von Neumann
could be right. We realized we needed an "Economic First Law of Motion." But none
exists in the text books. So we invented one: It starts with "Trade or die."
Indeed, Mike had spearheaded an effort to build our proud agent-based "Partecon"
model with agents and a set of goods. Agents had to trade within a given period or
die.
Is this "trade or die" rule sensible? Yes. (It is the economic analogue of "inertia" in
fact.)
It is 50,000 years ago. I have caught a rabbit today, you have caught nothing today.
"I'll give you half my rabbit today if you'll give me an equal weight of what you catch
in the next while," I offer you. You accept. Note that credit has just been created, for
you owe me a share of whatever you catch in the next while, say a month.
Then, 50,000 years ago, with food scarce and problematic, we trade or die. If there
are several goods and hunting and gathering, we hunt, gather (i.e. produce food) and
trade or die. Sometimes we trade for what we like more but do not have, traded for
what we have too much of, which is the economist's advantages of trade and
Edgeworth box.
So we have a first law of economic motion: Trade or Die, within some bounded
period is the roughly conserved average economic inertia. Then that first law states:
In the absence of outside forces, the total rate of trade in the clan will be, on average,
constant — like Newton's first law. Note clan GDP is constant.
Now let salt emerge as a favored good we all want and use as money to facilitate
trade among many parties with diverse goods and preferences.
Now let paper money emerge. The Chinese were the first to invent it, and the
emperor, it seems, entranced, printed vast amounts and induced fantastic, ruinous
inflation.
Which brings us to the "money supply." In a simplest, steady state economic theory,
if the money supply suddenly doubles, more money in our hands chases the same
number of goods, so prices double. If this price doubling were to happen in an
instant, the average rate of trade remains constant. The Economic First Law would
hold.
A Downward Spiral? Economics Made Too Simple : 13.7: Cosmos And Culture : NPR Page 2 of 4
http://www.npr.org/blogs/13.7/2011/07/25/138671362/a-downward-spiral-economics-made-too-simple 7/25/2011
But the steady state economic theory is wrong. Price changes lag a change in money
supply. Suppose instead a slow, steady increase in the money supply. What will
really happen in this case is that prices will indeed rise, but with a lag, say of eight
months or so.
Then, given a slowly increasing money supply and a lag in price rises, we really do
have more money per good at their current prices, even as money supply continues
to slowly increase.
So what happens? We really do purchase more goods and produce more goods to
match. In short, the total average rate of trades increases, and increases steadily if
the money supply continues to increase and prices continue to lag.
We have our second economic law of motion: An increasing money supply and
lagging prices increases (positively accelerates) the average rate of trade. The
economy grows, clan GDP grows and there is slow inflation. The increasing money
supply and lagging price increases is the analogue of F = MA, an economic force
acting to accelerate the First economic law of motion of constant rate of trade. The
appropriate integral of this force will be the analogue of economic energy added to
the economy.
But conversely, and critically, if money supply gradually decreases and price drops
lag, we really have less money per good and so purchase less and produce less. Trade
slows, or decelerates. In short, the "velocity of money" slows, GDP drops and
economic energy is drained from the economy.
Then what has driven so much growth in the First World since WWII? In some part,
there has been a global fluctuating increase in debt, from credit card debt, to
mortgage debt, to sovereign debt. This has slowly increased the money supply with
lagging price increases, and so driven an increase of trade, i.e. GDP growth.
I suspect, with most of us, that the debt rubber band is very stretched. We have only
to look at Greece, Ireland, Spain, Portugal, Italy and our own mushrooming debt.
At some point, say now, you do not repay my half-rabbit in a month but in five years.
I'm no longer willing to extend credit to you.
We may be there now. A credit bubble may be about to start a long contraction with
price drops lagging, sapping economic energy from our First World economy in a
long downward spiral.
This world is not this simple. I'm sure von Neumann would smile, even if he liked
this version of money as economic energy. But I doubt he would think the above is
entirely wrong.
A Downward Spiral? Economics Made Too Simple : 13.7: Cosmos And Culture : NPR Page 3 of 4
http://www.npr.org/blogs/13.7/2011/07/25/138671362/a-downward-spiral-economics-made-too-simple 7/25/2011
A Downward Spiral? Economics Made Too Simple : 13.7: Cosmos And Culture : NPR Page 4 of 4
http://www.npr.org/blogs/13.7/2011/07/25/138671362/a-downward-spiral-economics-made-too-simple 7/25/2011
For daily notes; adjunct to calendar; in lieu of handwriting notes in Day-Timer
Subscribe to:
Post Comments (Atom)
Blog Archive
-
▼
2011
(76)
-
▼
July
(18)
- A Downward Spiral? Economics Made Too Simple by ST...
- The GOP’s fuzzy math By Matt Miller
- Koolhaas, Delirious in Beijing By NICOLAI OUROUSSOFF
- The Hot List: A Single Pleasure Ere Summer Fades B...
- 3 Grown-Up Books For The Hogwarts Grad by ANNIE RO...
- THE PRODUCER'S PERSPECTIVE SUMMER READING LIST fr...
- Grill Dome’s Demonstration Chicken adapted from Ta...
- Meeting in the Middle for a Velvety Cheesecake By ...
- Five myths about the debt ceiling By Bruce Bartlett
- July 7, 2011, 12:01 am How Health Insurance Af...
- First Study of Its Kind Shows Benefits of Providin...
- What Obama Wants By PAUL KRUGMAN
- The Unexamined Society By DAVID BROOKS
- The Mother of All No-Brainers By DAVID BROOKS
- Big Business Leaves Deficit to Politicians By DAVI...
- Thirty Books Everyone Should Read Before They’re T...
- Lonely Voyage of Player, Piano and Audience By NAT...
- Operating Instructions: The Supreme Court shows co...
-
▼
July
(18)
No comments:
Post a Comment